Important
articles appeared in Economic and Political Weekly
1.
The 10% Rule and the LoP: Can Conventions Circumvent Law?
2. The “New” Planning Commission
3. The Reformed ‘Planning Commission’
4. Assam-Nagaland Border Violence
5. Cleaning Ganga River
6. Taking on ISIS
7. The Scottish Path to Independence
The 10% Rule
and the LoP: Can Conventions Circumvent Law?
The
speaker has decided to follow conventions rather than jurisprudence in her
decision not to accord the "leader of opposition" status to the
leader of the Congress legislative party in the Lok Sabha. Conventions cannot
supersede the law as various judgments point out. Comparisons to other
legislatures elsewhere in the world also suggest the inapplicability of the 10%
rule in appointing the LoP.
The results of the 16th Lok
Sabha elections had brought up a legal conundrum apropos the office of the
“leader of opposition” (LoP) in Parliament. The Congress Party, despite
securing the second highest number of seats in the Lok Sabha (44 seats), has
fallen short of what has been claimed as a minimum requirement of 10% of the
overall seats in the Lower House, to get its parliamentary party leader to
occupy the post of LoP. The office of the LoP is not a constitutional office in
the sense that it has not been created by the Constitution and owes its
existence to parliamentary convention which accords the leader of the largest
opposition party to that post.1
On 19 August this year, the
speaker of the current Lok Sabha Sumitra Mahajan affirmed that the appointment
to the post of LoP had to fulfil the 10% rule. The speaker is right in
noting the precedents of the 1980 and 1984 Lok Sabha, which did not have an
LoP. The second largest party in 1980 was the Lok Dal (Janata Secular) and in
1984 it was the Telugu Desam Party, both of whom secured 41 and 30 seats,
respectively. But the question remains if the precedents were simply based on
convention rather than the law. Conventions are non-legal rules regulating the
way in which legal rules shall be applied. In Supreme Court AoR Association,2 the Court explained that the scope of
a convention (in context of the Constitution) was to fill up the gaps and to
solve problems of interpretation since a great deal may be left unsaid.
Therefore, conventions are to supplement legislation for convenience,3 and cannot supplant it, and holding
the tradition of the 10% rule to be mandatory is tantamount to supplanting the
express provision of having greatest numerical strength in Parliament in the
law as we shall discuss later in the article.
The Role of the LoP
It is necessary to recall
British academic Ivor Jennings’ words, “Democratic Government demands not only
a parliamentary majority but also a parliamentary minority”.4 The Gauhati High Court has also stated
that an LoP is the one who carries more responsibility than a cabinet minister
when monitoring the function of the government,5 since the person occupying that post
has to criticise, find fault and present alternative proposals/policies with no
power to implement them.
The LoP is a part of the
committees to recommend the appointment of members and/or chiefs to the
official posts recognised in the statutes, for instance the Right to
Information (RTI) Act, 2005, the
National Human Rights Commission Act7 and the Central Vigilance Commission
(CVC) Act.
Laws Pertaining to
LoP
Until 1969, the practice
followed in the Rajya Sabha was to call the leader of the party in opposition
with the largest number of members as the LoP, without according her/him any
formal recognition, status or privilege. Prior to the 1977 general elections to
the Lok Sabha, except for a brief spell of one year (December 1969-December
1970), there had been no official opposition in the sense of the term that is
used in the parliamentary system of government.
But since the enactment of
Salary and Allowances of Leaders of Opposition in Parliament Act, 1977
(hereinafter “the 1977 Act”), the LoPs in the Rajya Sabha and the Lok Sabha are
now accorded statutory recognition and given salary and certain other
facilities and amenities.9 The
1977 Act defines the position as that member of the Lok Sabha or Rajya Sabha as
the case may be, who is for the time being the leader in that House of the
party in opposition to the central government having (a) the greatest numerical
strength and (b) recognised as such by the speaker of the Lok Sabha or the
chairman of the council of states as the case may be, which is similar to
counterpart provisions in the Maharashtra,10 Punjab,11 Arunachal Pradesh,12 Mizoram,13 and Jharkhand14 state assemblies.
However, Tripura’s law
mentions only about the numerical strength and does not say anything about
recognition by the speaker. Haryana’s law only mentions about the recognition
by the speaker, and Nagaland’s corresponding law mentions the requirement of a
minimum number of members, i e, 10 in number. Interestingly,
the law in Nagaland defines the LoP as a member of the state legislative
assembly, who is for the time being the leader of the party in opposition to
the ruling government having the largest and required numerical strength and
recognised as such by the speaker of the assembly. Whereas the LoP Act uses the
phrase “greatest numerical strength and recognised as such by the Speaker…”.
Therefore, it could be said that the 1977 Act does not talk about any minimum
threshold that is required to be satisfied in order for the numerically largest
party in opposition to the government to choose their leader in the House as
the LoP.
The CVC Act and RTI Act
define a leader of opposition to be the one, when no such leader has been so
recognised, to include the leader of the single largest group in opposition of
the government in the Lok Sabha.
Constitutional
Debates
During the Constituent
Assembly debates, Z H Lari proposed an amendment to draft Article 86, which
dealt with the allowances to the members of the legislatures after the
commencement of the Constitution. It stipulated that the LoP should be entitled
to get salary payable to a minister without cabinet rank.17 The speaker had highlighted the
importance of the LoP, saying that the entity shall make the party government
realise that they have to face public opinion whenever they take policy and
administrative decisions and by contending opposing views. The speaker pointed
out that the amendment moved must be crystallised in the Constitution to erode
the impression that there is to be only one party rule.
No member who spoke for or
against the amendment argued that there is no need for an opposition. In fact,
the reasons why the amendment was not accepted were: (i) those opposed to the
amendment felt that merely recognising the LoP does not mean that the post
shall be able to organise a party on its own, (ii) there was not going to be
any embargo on Parliament in the future from providing for the salary or
recognising the LOP, if it deemed necessary.19
It is clear that objection
(i) did not imagine a situation where the LoP is selected from a party in
minority in the legislature body (which is the current practice). Rather it
thought of the LoP being recognised firstly, then, that leader would organise a
party in opposition. The contention (ii) is upheld by the enactment of the 1977
Act.
LoP in Foreign
Jurisdictions
The UK parliamentary system
recognises the LoP to be one who is usually the leader of the political party
with the second-largest number of seats in the House of Commons. Whereas, in Australia the post is the
leader of the party or coalition of parties which is the next largest after the
ruling party in the House of Representatives, and which is made up of members
who do not support the government.21 The Constitution of Barbados
recognises the post to be the one who commands the support of a majority of those
members who do not support the government, and if there is no such person, the
member of that House who commands the support of the largest single group.22 The South African Constitution
provides for the recognition of the leader of the largest opposition party in
the assembly as LoP.23
Judicial Cases
In the case of A
K Subbaih vs Karnataka Legislature Secretariat, the Karnataka High Court
held that the convention of having an LOP whose party has secured a minimum
one-tenth of the effective strength of the House, is for the House to continue
to adhere to or depart from it. And that the court will have no jurisdiction to
entertain any petition regarding this issue.
In the case of the Kailash
Nath Singh vs Speaker,24 the
Allahabad High Court opined that even in the absence of any guideline on how to
accord recognition to a member as the LoP, it must be done as per the
prevailing practice and convention. In this particular case, the petitioner was
selected to be the LoP when his party secured 92 seats. But due to a split in
the party, two groups were formed, with the one with more number of members
voting for respondent number 2 to be selected as the LoP. The speaker
recognised respondent number 2 (in the case) to be the new LoP. The court held
that the principle adopted by the speaker that the party in opposition with the
largest numerical strength can choose a LoP was consistently followed when
recognising the petitioner and then respondent number 2 as the LoPs and hence
the speaker had acted within his jurisdiction.
The Patna High Court was
presented with the issue as to whether there is a definite requirement of the
10% rule in order to name the LoP. Section 2 of the Bihar Legislature (Leaders
of Opposition Salary and Allowances) Act, 1977 required that for a person to be
the LoP needed to be the (i) leader of a party having the greatest numerical
strength in the assembly, and (ii) be recognised as such by the speaker. The
Patna High Court, on the other hand, held that the speaker had to follow
practice and convention. It also held that there was no provision in the Act
which enjoins the speaker to recognise the leader of a party with the greatest
numerical strength, to be the LoP.25
Conclusions
The LoP is effectively a
“shadow” prime minister who has the preferential right to address the House. It
is recognised that a democratic form of government would be reduced to a farce
if there were no strong opposition.
While the central law and state laws defining
the LoP are specific with respect to who is to be accorded such status, the
“10% minimum argument” is not substantiated by any such inference from these
laws. The Leaders and Chief Whips of Recognised Parties and Groups in
Parliament (Facilities) Act, 1998 does not explicitly mention any such 10% rule
and the fixed minimum number required to accord the status of a “recognised
party”, i e, 55 has nothing to do with the definition of the LoP in the 1977
Act. The Act crystallises what the framers of the Constitution contemplated
about the provision of salaries which could be made whenever the need for
opposition was recognised. The provision of recognition by the speaker is
pertinent to be satisfied, but it is submitted that the satisfaction of the 10%
rule is something that may be merely, and at most, a convention not binding on
the speaker. In light of the necessity of opposition in legislatures, this
convention need not be adhered to. The provisions for the declaration of the
LoP in the UK, Australia, Barbados and South Africa also recognise the leader
of the party in opposition to the government with the maximum numerical
strength to be the LoP.
The decisions of the high
court are also not helpful since in (i) the Subbaiah case there was no provision produced;
(ii) the Kailash Nath case
had provisions that provided only that the LoP meant to be the member of the
legislative house (assembly) who is for the time being recognised as such by
the speaker and did not provide for any other criteria of according such
recognition,27 and
(iii) the Kapoori case, it
was submitted that (a) if the speaker is allowed the power to recognise, then
he/she cannot allow the LoP to be selected even if the largest minority has
more than 10% of the overall seats and (b) allowing such power to the speaker
undermined the qualification of being the “maximum minority”, so that even if
the party is the largest minority it could still not be recognised.
In my view, the recognition
of speaker is only to put an official authorisation to the selection of the
LoP. This is evident in the debates to the Constituent Assembly, where no one
objected to there being an LoP but preferred that the Parliament provided for
salaries to them in the future. Hence, the Act of 1977 cannot be meant to only
provide for salaries and to not recognise the requirement for a LoP.
It is the duty of the
government of the day to form opinions to take actions and the only way it
could know that the opinion is right is if the complete liberty of
contradicting and disproving the opinion is given to others in Parliament. If
there is any error on the part of government, it could be corrected only by
discussion and debate, for the purposes of which the office of LoP assumes
extreme importance.
The “New”
Planning Commission
The
body that is to replace the Planning Commission must build on the strengths of
the existing one even as it addresses the many existing deficiencies.
Prime
Minister Narendra Modi announced the demise of the Planning Commission from the
ramparts of the Red Fort on Independence Day. As the nation debates the form
and content of the institution to replace the Planning Commission, it may be
useful to reflect on the immediate context that precipitated the disbanding, as
also to reiterate certain functions of the Planning Commission that will need
to be performed by its replacement. I will draw mainly, but not only, upon my
five years as Member, Planning Commission during 2009-14.
Classifying
Institutions
One
way of classifying institutions is in terms of the balance between their
potential positive power (PPP) and potential negative power (PNP). Potential
positive power may be broadly understood to mean the capacity and power to
enforce or facilitate positive change that would hasten the achievement of
national goals. Potential negative power, on the other hand, refers to the
capacity or power to obstruct, delay or derail positive reform, in cases where
such reform threatens entrenched vested interests, status quo or business as
usual.[1] The exercise of PNP is often a ruse
to foster corrupt practices, but it can also be an exercise of wanton power for
its own sake, reflecting a perverse sense of power-induced pleasure.
The
two institutions with perhaps the highest quotient of both PPP and PNP in the
government of India have, especially in recent years, been the Planning
Commission and the Ministry of Finance. In my five years in the Planning
Commission, I saw many instances of PNP and how this became a source of great
resentment against the Planning Commission, both among state governments and
central ministries. Of course, at times, the Planning Commission acted with
sagacity in checking profligacy of funds and schemes. But there were many cases
where in-principle approvals, investment clearances, grants-in-aid and other
decisions appeared to smack of bureaucratic red tape, more than an application
of mind motivated by the broader national interest and effectiveness of
functioning. There were also visible vestiges of the old Stalinist command and
control, inspector raj mindset.[2]
The
Expenditure Finance Committee (EFC) meetings held to approve expenditure on new
schemes typically saw the Planning Commission representatives play an
obstructionist role, at times raising completely specious objections that
revealed not merely non-application of mind but also lack of due diligence and
requisite homework on their part. This led to huge delays in the passage,
through the corridors of power, of many an innovative idea for reform of
government. States too were displeased with their chief ministers having to go
through the annual ritual of obtaining approval of their Annual Plans at Yojana
Bhavan. An empty ritual it was, for neither did the Planning Commission have
much to add in finances to the state’s Plan, even the well-meaning advice of
the Planning Commission generally tended to be ignored because of the overall
context of the Annual Plan “approval” meeting in which the advice was being
given. It is clear that reaction to this unrelenting exercise of negative power
has finally reached a crescendo, with the institution itself suffering a
demise.
To
my mind, it is this negativity that is the chief cause for the Prime Minister’s
action, more than the oft-repeated notion that the Planning Commission had to
go because it was a “socialist” vestige, an anachronism in the capitalist
economy that is India today. Indeed, the role of the Planning Commission in
India in recent decades has had nothing to do with keeping the commanding heights
of the economy with the public sector. If anything, quite to the contrary, it
has been a great proponent of the private sector and Public-Private
Partnerships (PPPs). So in understanding its demise and anticipating the roles
of its replacement, this ideological lens is not of much use.
Such
a view, that has been expressed, not only by the right but also surprisingly by
the left, in any case, overlooks the work of Yale political scientist David
Cameron (1978) and Princeton economist Dani Rodrik, which decisively show that
even advanced capitalist economies, virtually without exception, are
characterised by massive and increasing role of government. As Rodrik (2012)
suggests, developing strong markets and open economies requires more
government, not less: “With very few exceptions, the more developed an economy,
the greater the share of its resources that is consumed by the public sector.
Governments are bigger and stronger not in the world’s poorest but in its most
advanced economies. The correlation between government size and per capita
income is remarkable tight. Rich countries have better functioning markets and
larger governments when compared to poor ones.”[3] If we take today’s advanced
economies and track the share of government expenditure in their economies over
time, Rodrik finds a steadily rising trend from 11% in 1870, 20% in1920, 28% in
1960, 40% in 1975 to around 35-60% today. And the higher shares are found in
more open economies because their citizens demand that governments compensate
them against the risk which international economic forces expose them to.
Our
view, therefore, is that to get a more concrete idea of the what the new
institution must do, it would be much more useful to focus on the many positive
roles that the Planning Commission played and which, perhaps, no other
institution in India is in a position to perform.
Seven
Key Roles
The
key arena where the new institution must play its part is in mediating
centre-state relations and pushing for a more devolved economy and polity in
India. Given the enormous diversity of India in social, cultural,
agro-ecological and economic terms, it becomes imperative to focus on the principle
of subsidiarity. Every effort needs to be made to find location-specific
solutions to problems, closest to where the problems exist. States must enjoy
maximum flexibility in this respect and there must be mechanisms that
facilitate learning across states. Despite all the exercise of negative power
that I alluded to earlier, the new institution is in a great position to draw
upon the very rich experience of the Planning Commission in each of these
respects.
In
my years at the Planning Commission, I saw innumerable instances of the
exercise of this positive power. I believe there are at least seven broad areas
in which the Planning Commission played an extremely positive role: one,
pioneering an inclusive planning process; two, facilitating and mainstreaming
reform; three, pushing decentralized planning forward by emphasising the
principle of subsidiarity in recognition of the deep diversity of India; four,
rationalizing the centrally sponsored schemes and introducing greater
flexibility within them; five, being the spokesperson of the states at the
centre; six, co-ordinating across, if not breaking down departmental silos
within the Government of India as also arbitrating disputes by taking a more
long-term and holistic view of issues; and seven, providing an independent
evaluation and critique of government programmes and policies. Each of these
roles will need to be taken over by the new institution replacing the Planning
Commission.
Inclusive
Planning
The
Twelfth Plan process saw a completely unprecedented architecture of plan
formulation. For the first time in the history of the Planning Commission, the
12 working groups on water, rural development and panchayati raj were chaired
by eminent experts from outside government and included the best minds and
practitioners from across central and state governments, academia, research
institutions, industry, civil society, and panchayati raj institutions. It was
clearly recognised that all wisdom does not reside within government and that
the best plans, programmes and policies could be made only with the active
involvement of those outside government. This was not mere tokenism in the name
of participation. Final decisions were made by these inclusive working groups.
For me, the true indicator of the success of this process was that even though
none of the players involved were fully happy with the final outcome, something
truly path-breaking was achieved. This only reflected the spirit of compromise
that is a hallmark of good governance, as a hard-fought consensus was thrashed
out among the members and the chair and co-chair, who was in each case the
senior-most official of the concerned department. Each side was compelled to
give up their own pet fundamentalisms in the interests of forging a consensus.
The result was a series of landmark proposals that constitute a paradigm shift
in water management in India, including the first-ever National Aquifer
Management Programme, a new approach to incentivise de-bureaucratisation of
large irrigation projects and irrigation management transfer to increase water
use efficiency, a new integrated approach to rural drinking water and
sanitation, a proposal to regularly audit the industrial water footprint and a
new “room-for-the-river” approach to flood management.
Facilitating
and Mainstreaming Reforms by States
Almost
all the innovations listed above were drawn from best practices pioneered by
state governments, who have led the reform process in our country in recent
years. The specific role of the Planning Commission was to enable the
mainstreaming, across the length and breadth of the country, of something that
was initially attempted only in one state or even a part of the state. I was
fortunate to have been able to build on many such initiatives. The National
Aquifer Management Programme, for example, emerged from the extraordinary
effort of a million farmers in Andhra Pradesh, who showed how sustainable
management of groundwater was possible once farmers understood the nature of
their aquifers. Despite the fact that India is the most groundwater dependent
country in the world (leaving China way behind) with around 30 million
groundwater structures (wells and tubewells), we have still not mapped our
aquifers at a scale that enables their sustainable management by the primary
stakeholders.
It
was the Planning Commission that helped the Ministry of Water Resources develop
a national programme that will enable aquifers all over India to be mapped for
the first time ever at a scale that will make it possible for them to be sustainably
managed. Another such initiative in which I was involved is the mainstreaming
of Gujarat’s greatly successful Jyotigram (separation of power feeders) scheme
that has already made a dramatic impact on the power situation in states like
Madhya Pradesh.
Promoting
Devolution
A
key role played by the Planning Commission over the years has been to promote
the cause of decentralized planning. In the Twelfth Plan period, this
culminated in the creation of a new centrally sponsored scheme called the Rajiv
Gandhi Panchayat Sashaktikaran Abhiyan (RGPSA). The RGPSA is based on the
conviction that panchayati raj institutions (PRIs) in India have suffered in
the absence of professional human resource support. This is perhaps the single
most important change I was part of during the 12th Plan,
although few among economic and political commentators seem even remotely aware
of it. Building upon an offer by the Ministry of Rural Development (MoRD), the
Planning Commission was able to carve out a massive increase in the allocation
for the Ministry of Panchayati Raj through a mere 1% reduction in the
allocation of the MoRD, which saw great merit in strengthening PRIs for
improving the quality of implementation of its own programmes.
Another
blow in favour of devolution and strengthening PRIs, initiated by the Planning
Commission, was the exercise to restructure the Backward Regions Grant Fund
(BRGF), the most important development programme providing untied funds to
PRIs. The exercise was about moving the BRGF to the sub-district level because
it is no longer meaningful to understand backwardness in India at the district
level, with many “advanced” districts enclosing pockets of intense backwardness
within them and many “backward” districts, containing very advanced sub-districts.
By focusing on sub-districts we would be able to zero in on the truly backward
regions of India.[4]
Greater
Flexibility in Schemes
A
major complaint of states over the years has been the great inflexibility of
centrally sponsored schemes (CSSs) and the rigid guidelines imposed upon them
by central ministries. We must begin by stating that contrary to popular belief
the Planning Commission hardly plays any discretionary function as far as fund
flows to states are concerned. This flow mainly takes place through CSSs but
these are controlled by the central ministries. We believe a certain number of
CSSs are required for the achievement of basic national goals like health,
education, sanitation, nutrition and drinking water. But there is a legitimate
concern about the proliferation of CSSs.
The
Planning Commission has played a stellar role in rationalizing the number of
CSSs, most recently through the work of the BK Chaturvedi Committee. The work
of the committee involved a process of widespread consultations with the
concerned ministries, States and other relevant stakeholders. This led to a
drastic reduction in the number of schemes, which many still regard as
inadequate but they overlook the fact that the Planning Commission has always
pushed hard for their reduction. The difficulty has been that finally it had to
go by the consensus possible with the ministries very keen to retain their pet
projects.
Even
more significant has been the contribution of the Planning Commission in
introducing significant flexibility in the guidelines of CSSs. Once again the
process involved extensive consultations with the States, as also with the best
civil society implementers in India. This has led to changes in the MGNREGA
guidelines, accepting suggestions of states for activities suited to their
conditions, as also works that enable synergy with agriculture in view of the
widespread (even if false, in view of the Planning Commission) complaint about
the adverse impact of MGNREGA on small and marginal farmers.
The
guidelines for sanitation were also modified to allow States to use
location-specific designs as per their ecological conditions. The guidelines
for the drinking water programme were tweaked to promote devolution on the
basis of a Management Devolution Index, which summarises the extent and quality
of devolution in drinking water management systems across states. Over and
above all these CSS specific changes, the Planning Commission introduced the
concept of a “flexi-fund” that would enable states to undertake innovative
projects across CSS silos.
Spokesperson
for the States
The
new institution set up to replace the Planning Commission must continue to play
this kind of role in support of the states in their hard negotiations with
central ministries. When the Chief Minister of Madhya Pradesh went on a fast,
raising a series of legitimate grievances of the state with the centre, the
Prime Minister asked me, as member-in-charge of Madhya Pradesh, to work with
all concerned Central ministries to hammer out an amicable solution. This was
done in record time, to the satisfaction of the aggrieved chief minister.
Similarly, at the request of the Chief Minister of Punjab, I chaired a
high-level expert group on waterlogging in Punjab. The group, consisting of the
nation’s best experts on the subject, conducted a thorough investigation of the
problem, in close partnership with the state government, and came out with a
package of solutions, which was generously supported by the Government of
India. Similar roles were played by other members in other contexts, which
illustrate how the Planning Commission can be an effective mediator and
problem-solver for States, rather than their tormentor.
Breaking
Departmental Silos
Water
is perhaps the sector that suffers the most from being broken down into
departmental silos. The Twelfth Plan has described it as “hydro-schizophrenia”,
where the left hand of drinking water does not know what the right hand of
irrigation is doing. The Plan document diagnoses the emerging crisis of
drinking water and so-called “slipped-back habitations” as emerging from the
fact that the same source that was providing drinking water to the habitation
was also being used for irrigation, a much larger guzzler of water. Again, the
fact that drinking water and sanitation were being run as separate programmes
meant that often there was no water in sanitary facilities and, in other
instances, the drinking water suffered bacterial pollution. All of these kinds
of issues were typically tackled by the Planning Commission by modifying
programme guidelines and seeking to bring greater convergence in action.
Independent
Critique and Evaluation
This
has been one of the most well-established roles of the Planning Commission over
the years. Given its unique position of being, in a sense, both inside and
outside government, the evaluations and critiques the Planning Commission
proffered of government programmes and policies, has had a more than academic
value and has often led to positive reforms in implementation. The Planning
Commission has drawn upon the best expertise available within academia to play
this role. The quality of these exercises has, however, not always been up to
the desired level and the new institution being set up must do better in this
regard. A crucial element that needs change is the ability to hire the best
available talent and being able to network with the best institutions, which
would give this exercise real credibility. This also makes it essential for
there to be such expertise available in-house so that it can draw in whatever
resources required, both from among academics and practitioners.
Conclusions
The
new institution that replaces the Planning Commission will need to play each
one of these crucial roles. However, it is also important that the negative
roles of the Planning Commission, such as approving the Annual Plans of the
states, should be done away with. The so-called “regulatory” role of being able
to veto EFC notes must also be eliminated. Each one of the positive functions
we have described earlier implies a think-tank role. But these functions cannot
be performed by just any other toothless think-tank. Their effective
performance demands that the institution be empowered in a way that enables it
to make a difference at the cutting edge of implementation. Otherwise the “new”
Planning Commission, whatever it may be named, will be reduced to a shadow of
its former self.
The Reformed ‘Planning Commission’
The
Way Forward
The
government must recognise that one source of China’s strategic economic growth
is an institution with strategic planning capacities, the National Development
and Reform Commission. The success of China with the NDRC tells us that fiscal
decentralisation, accountability mechanisms, experimentation, learning, and
openness to expertise form the core of any institution that seeks to provide
vision and strategic economic planning. Further, strategic planning
institutions in Asian economies, like India’s Planning Commission, have helped
deal with various regional and global economic crises; a lesson we must keep in
mind.
Santosh
Mehrotra (santoshmeh@gmail.com)
teaches at the Centre for Labour and Informal Sector Studies, Jawaharlal Nehru
University, New Delhi.
This
article is a longer and revised version of an article published in The Hindu.
The
National Democratic Alliance (NDA)-led government has decided to abolish the
Planning Commission, and create a new institution in its place. This requires a
redefinition of the functions of the old organisation. The following functions
could be considered, in the light of concerns expressed by the government.
First, it should function as the foremost government think tank. Second, it
will need to continue to prepare five-year plans, or even perhaps slightly
longer term perspective plans. Third, it needs to give a more effective voice
to state governments. The erstwhile function of pre-appraising all projects
from all ministries should be retired, except in areas where it has special
expertise (as discussed later).
Think
Tank Function
There
is one role that the current Planning Commission has barely managed to perform
– systematically collecting best practices in policy or programme design from
states, and then replicating successful models across the country. India is a
veritable laboratory for good practices within states in every sector. But so
removed is the culture of learning from our administrative system that since
independence we have not managed to institutionalise any method of learning
across states. If learning across states is to be systematised, then the
Planning Commission would be the appropriate body for this purpose. But that
requires that it plays a much greater strategic role than it has played so far.
Since a strategic role with actual power is what the National Development and
Reform Commission (NDRC) has achieved in China, the Chinese experience is
salutary for India.
One
thing that the Chinese experience teaches us is that after the economic reforms
began in 1979, the Chinese government, after the name of the State Planning
Commission was changed to the NDRC (in 2003), the institution became more
powerful than it was during the pre-reform era. It is possible in China to
create a strategic, powerful role for NDRC as it has a strong planning function
in several key areas (natural resources, guiding Chinese embassies on economic
matters and promoting economic diplomacy).
It
is essential to place the transition to the NDRC in context. First, the
strategic planning function for the economy as a whole remained with the NDRC.
Second, five-year plans continued to be prepared after 2003 just as they had
been prepared before 1979. In other words, they did not move to a mere
long-term perspective plan alone. The problem with a long-term perspective plan
is that it has rather little practical value other than laying out a vision. It
is not a usable document. Of course, the current five-year plans may also be
criticised for not having practical value. However, that can be changed if the
NDA government so decides, by making an annual strategic evaluation of
programmes and projects a regular phenomenon to check if line ministries
achieved targets. It would then become an important tool in the hands of the
prime minister, as chair of the new Planning Commission, to monitor progress
(well beyond the mere collection of data that is put on the Delivery Monitoring
Unit created by the previous Prime Minister’s Office (PMO) in 2009) towards
targets. This monitoring role cannot be left to the line ministry, since the
line ministry is an interested party, and its leadership is bound to defend its
performance. Since the prime minister (and consequently the PMO) can instruct
the line ministry to either redesign the programmes that are not delivering or
scrap it, this role for the new Planning Commission is consistent with the
transfer of the financial allocation function away from the current Planning
Commission to the Ministry of Finance.
Some
make the argument that if the new Planning Commission does not have financial
allocation powers, then its powers of persuasion will be accordingly
restricted. This argument is considerably weakened as the new Planning
Commission’s chairperson will still remain the prime minister, who could hold
the line ministries to account. In any case, the powers of persuasion have not
worked very well so far even with the current Planning Commission’s financial
allocation powers (and the new government is not persuaded that the new
Planning Commission should retain that power).
Fiscal
Decentralisation
There
is another lesson for India from the Chinese system. One of the most important
differences between the Chinese and Indian fiscal arrangements between the
centre and states is that China has become, since the 1979 economic reforms,
considerably more decentralised fiscally (both in relation to its past and
vis-à-vis India), and its economic growth is caused by this phenomenon. China
is highly decentralised fiscally, despite having a fully unitary constitution,
as well as a one-party government. However, India remains one of the most
fiscally centralised federal systems in the world. The reason perhaps for this
situation is that the Indian state inherited in 1947 over 600 principalities
from British rule, which needed to be woven together into an Indian Union, and
the founding fathers of the Constitution created a highly centralised state, at
least fiscally. In fact, it has been normal to describe the Indian Constitution
as being federal, but with strong unitary features.
Under
the circumstances, the Planning Commission’s role reinforces fiscal
centralisation in India, with its centrally-sponsored schemes (CSSs) (which
even after the rationalisation following the B K Chaturvedi Committee report
still number 67, and account for the main mechanism of transfer of programmatic
resources to the states of India). The one-size-fits-all design of the CSSs,
which has long been the source of much resentment for state governments, has only
recently begun to be loosened up with the share of “untied funds” rising to 20%
of total plan funds under each CSS. In fact, most of the allocations by the
Planning Commission so far have been made under the CSSs. It is the CSSs that
have been the source of the newly-elected central government’s problems with
the Planning Commission, and intensified the demand for disbanding the Planning
Commission. However, that would amount to throwing the baby out with the
bathwater.
In
China, the high level of fiscal decentralisation with retention of revenues
generated by provinces and also township and county governments (the latter
being the equivalent to India’s panchayati raj institutions/urban local
bodies), combines effectively with the strategic planning role of the NDRC.
Unfortunately, we have had the worst of all worlds, with a fiscally centralised
centre on the one hand, and a Planning Commission that has historically
promoted one-size-fits-all CSSs.
Experimentation
and Learning
There
is another big difference between China and India. What is notable is the
tradition that the Chinese state established as part of planning strategic
reform: the tradition of carrying out nationwide reforms only after experiments
to pilot the reforms in different states. Thus, farmland had been collectivised
in the late 1950s and individual plots were abolished. Economic reforms in
China began in 1979 with agrarian reforms. Collective farms were experimentally
broken up and leased to individual households for a 30-year period, but this
programme never went to scale until it had been piloted in a number of
communities in a few provinces. This model of experimentation was repeatedly
followed for other reforms.
In
India, on the other hand, experimentation of this kind is an exception, not the
rule. The real problem is that our ability to judge whether a proposed
programme design will actually deliver the expected results remains low.
Ministries typically prepare programmes without explicitly exploring
alternative programme designs to achieve the same results. Programmes are
devised with “top down” designs, where the centre provides funds and the states
implement. Decades of experience demonstrates that this method of planning or
programme design does not work.
The
implication is that the new, reformed Indian Planning Commission must be
responsible for conducting programmes on a pilot basis using alternate design
elements before they are rolled out on a national level.
A
second function that the reformed Planning Commission must perform is to
institutionalise the learning from different states about good policy and
programme design. For example, the extension system in most of the country
collapsed over the last quarter of a century, except in a minority of states.
However, Gujarat managed to sustain the extension-worker model with impressive
results. The Planning Commission was supposed to perform this learning
function, but it is rare for state governments to repeatedly follow successful
models that have been shown to work. The previous Planning Commission had
recognised these problems, but was unable to implement reform. The new
government can change things if the prime minister wishes to take this role
seriously by imposing such solutions on the line ministries, and following up
with incentive funds for the purpose.
It
is highly likely that the Expenditure Reforms Commission will rationalise
expenditures further, beyond the reduction in the number of CSSs that was done
by the previous Planning Commission. It is also likely that the scope of cash
transfers may well increase significantly, while the scope of project-based
subsidies might decline correspondingly. The new Planning Commission should be
responsible for conducting pilots of the new cash transfer schemes that will be
conceived.
Giving
States a Greater Voice
The
existing Planning Commission had long played a role in an interaction with
states. State governments have come every year to the Planning Commission in
the last quarter of the financial year to discuss both their economic and
social performance as well as annual plan allocations. However, this role of
the Planning Commission has been a source of resentment between the centre and
the states.
The
National Development Council has been an appropriate forum for the voice of
states, but has not met frequently enough – this is one problem. The second
problem with regard to interactions between the Planning Commission and the
states is that there is no systematic discussion forum for policy reform, in
specific sectors, in consultation with the states. These discussions are often
conducted by central line ministries, but only with regard to the CSSs that are
implemented by the states. There is need for a central forum, institutionalised
in the reformed Planning Commission, where the states discuss the new areas of
concentration.
What
could be the areas of sectoral expertise that the new Planning Commission
should develop?
(i)
The Twelfth Five-Year Plan has emphasised quite explicitly for the first time
since the economic reforms began the need for an industrial policy. The new
government has also emphasised the need for foreign direct investment to
promote manufacturing, especially for export markets. One of the roles of the
new Planning Commission should be to bring together relevant stakeholders for
the 17 sectors identified in the manufacturing chapter of the Twelfth Plan on a
systematic and regular basis so that industrial policy does not remain the
preserve of the Department for Industrial Policy and Planning alone. This would
be similar to the role NDRC plays in China.
(ii)
The other areas should be: Education and skill development; health; nutrition
(none of which are NDRC priorities in China); agriculture and rural
development; water; energy policy; transport and logistics. Sectoral
Expertise
One
of the long-standing criticisms of the Planning Commission has been that it has
lost its professional expertise because it is staffed by generalist Indian
Administrative Service (IAS) and Indian Economic Service (IES) officers mostly
at senior levels. Its ability to persuade states about good practices or become
a knowledge hub based on research and professional experience is quite limited.
Staff move in and out of the Planning Commission like in any other ministry.
Therefore, it has always remained a question as to what its value added is over
and above a sectoral ministry. By contrast, in China the staff of the NDRC
spend their entire careers in it within a given division, and in this manner
develop professional expertise.
Generalist
officers must be responsive to outside expert opinion on the design of policies
and programmes, which happens rarely in the Planning Commission (except in the
run-up to plan preparation through working groups, but their opinions can get
buried in the final plan draft). The real question remains – how will the new
Planning Commission be staffed, so that specialised expertise dominates in the
priority sector areas outlined? To start with, expertise could be sourced from
within the government. However, lateral entrants must be encouraged on a
greater scale than has been possible. So a widespread programme of lateral
entry at different levels would have to be encouraged. However, the implication
is that the remuneration and overall package to such lateral entries must match
what they might be able to command in the market.
One
last word. Latin American and African economies that used to have planning
commissions or equivalents until the late 1970s and abolished them in the
1980s, have begun regretting their decisions. In contrast, most Asian economies
still retain the equivalent of our Planning Commission. An important reason why
Asian economies have emerged rapidly from the regional/global economic crises
in 1997 and 2008 is because they retained their strategic planning capacity,
and institutions that embody that capacity. The Government of India should note
that bitter lesson, so that we do not live to regret the mistakes committed by
most Latin American economies.
Assam-Nagaland
Border Violence
Role of militants and the state
The
violence that erupted in the Assam-Nagaland border a month back has been the
fallout of poor governance by the respective state governments. Their
complicity in the violence is linked to the interest of extremist elements who
fuel insurgency by alienating people of both the states.
Nazimuddin
Siddiqui (nazim10dream@gmail.com)
is a research scholar at the Department of Sociology, Gauhati University,
Assam.
Out
of eight north-east states Assam has seen most violence in recent times, to the
point that violence is now synonymous with Assam. “A number of Armed conflicts
smoulder in this frontier region: the outside world is aware of a few of them,
but only people living in remote war zones- and paying a price with their blood
and tears know the others ” (Baruah 2005). The large scale brutality in
Assam-Nagaland border in August 2014 came in only after a lull of few days
since 57 Muslims were horrendously shot dead by Bodo militants in Baksa
district of Assam.
Beginning
of the present conflict
The
ferocity started in the Assam-Nagaland border region with a dispute of land
between two individuals. Of the two, one was from the ex-tea tribe community of
Assam and the other one was from the Naga community. The dispute was apparently
settled but the situation flared up with an alleged abduction on 26 July 2014
of two children - Filson Kujur of Green Valley High School and Ajay Gad of
Gholapani Little Flower High School who are studying in the tenth and ninth
standard respectively. The incident happened in the Assam Nagaland border
under Dhanashiri subdivision of Golaghat district of Assam.
In
the initial phase about 20,000 people from various organisations undertook
democratic protests to put their demand for the release of the abducted
students. The protestors went on to surround the 155 Central Reserve Police
Force (CRPF) camp which led to baton charge by the CRPF on the protestors. At
that time NSCN (National Socialist Council of Nagaland) extremists who were
hiding about 200 m away started firing indiscriminately with sophisticated
weapons on the unarmed protestors. In addition to firing, the Naga
miscreants started torching houses which led to the evacuation of many
villagers. The firing and torching of houses continued in the following days.
17 people were killed and there was a massive exodus has led to the
internal displacement of more than 10,000 people.
Lack
of police action
Presently
the disrupted zone of Assam-Nagaland border areas are under the supervision of
neutral central forces. But the forces could provide no security of life and
property to the villagers of the conflict zone. Villagers claimed that while
the NSCN extremists were firing indiscriminately on the unarmed villagers
the CRPF were mute spectators and didn’t take any preventive action.
In
a specific instance Naga extremists allegedly shot bullets in the presence of
none other than a Director General of Police (DGP) and the Superintendent of
Police (SP) of Assam Police. Sanglasung, 2 no. Chainpur, Lachitgaon,
Romanbasti, Jahajigaon, Kempur, Rojapukhuri, Komolpur, Majgaon etc. are a few
villages along the border which were burned to the ground. The situation
is so frazzled that the Naga government had issued an advisory to the Naga
people not to travel through Golaghat district which is the violence torn
district. Night curfew had been imposed for an indefinite period in the
belt. Various student organisations of Assam had started economic blockade by
blocking the crucial National highway 39 which connects Nagaland to Assam. This
blockade will result a severe loss to the economy of Nagaland and
Manipur.
Root
of the Conflict and Politics
Conflicts
between Nagas and Assamese in the Assam-Nagaland border areas are in no way a
new experience. The first Naga assailment came in on 29 December 1959 on
government property at Uriamghat, Assam. That day which may, on record, be
cited as the first incidence of atrocities was perpetrated by a section of Naga
militants on Assam, one forest office was looted and then set ablaze. These
series of conflict has been enduring since the last 50 years or so and since
then not less than 300 people killed in these conflicts. The central issue of
present conflict in sector B and sector D of Assam Nagaland border area is
claims and counter claims over land. Land of hill areas is not suitable for
cultivation and therefore a section of Naga miscreants are parsimoniously
looking upon the plains which are mostly inhabited by an ethnic group known as
ex-tea tribes.
Continuing
the tradition of massacre, invariably even this time the victims of violence
are “…innocent people who had been struggling hard for survival like most other
victims of politically-oriented violence” (Hussain 1995). “….in an official
statement in the Assam Assembly provided the following statistics: over
86,886.12 hectares of land of Assam have been encroached upon. Nagaland alone
has been accused of encroaching 59,159.77 hectares” (Economic Times 2014).
A case is already pending in the Supreme Court regarding the dispute of
boundaries between Assam and Nagaland. Supreme Court appointed a mediator team
to prepare a report and the same also was submitted to the apex court. The
damaging encumbrance came to the mediating process when the apex court asked
for feedback from the parties, i.e. Assam and Nagaland. The feedback is yet to
be submitted to the court by both the parties and the process has thus stranded
in deadlock.
The
administration in denial
Violence
in the border areas are occurring repeatedly due to poor governance by the
respective state governments. “Governance today encompasses much more than mere
rule or administration, it represents a commitment to democratic institutions,
processes and values in order to ensure economic, political and social
security”(Hussain 2003).
After
the violence, both the governments have been playing blame game on the issue.
The Assam government alleged that much of its territorial land has been
encroached by some Nagas. In addition to that, the Naga government has
legitimised the process by building offices, hospitals, educational
institutions etc. on the encroached land. There have been instances where the
respective state governments carried out dialogues to resolve the issue. But
these superficial initiatives remained largely inconclusive.
Role
of Naga militants
It
is alleged that the last incident of violence was spurred by the NSCN militant
groups of Nagaland. As Baruah (2005) argued, “The Naga conflict began with
India’s independence in 1947: Naga leaders rejected the idea that their land,
which was under a special dispensation during colonial rule, could simply pass
on to Indian hands at the end of British colonial rule”. In the 1950s it turned
in to an armed conflict.
However
a separate state Nagaland came in to being in 1963 but the conflict continued
over the decades. One of the important objectives of NSCN-IM (National
Socialist Council of Nagaland-Isak-Muivah) is to establish a “Greater Nagalim”
engulfing all Naga inhabited areas in neighboring states i.e. Assam, Manipur,
and Arunachal Pradesh in addition to Nagaland. They even want to include some
portions of Myanmar which are inhabited by Nagas into the“Greater Nagalim”. “The proposed
Nagalim spreads over approximately 1, 20,000 sq km in contrast to the
present state of Nagaland that has an area of 16,527 sq km”.
With a vision of Nagalim this militant group is in a constant endeavor to push
the boundaries of Nagaland towards the plains of Assam. Even the state
government of Nagaland is allegedly in collaboration with the militant
groups.
In
1985 a full fledge gun battle between Assam police and Naga police took place
in the border areas and it is alleged that Naga police were accompanied by the
NSCN militants in the gun battle. Killings, looting, kidnappings, threatening,
etc. are some common phenomena in the Assam-Nagaland border areas. The
Naga insurgency still persists due to lack of political will on the part of
Nagaland government. “Mainstream Naga politicians do not want the insurgency to
end because once that happens militia leaders would compete with them for
elected office” (Misra 2000). Civil societies had been in constant endeavor for
a long lasting peace in the region but governments of both the states are busy
playing the blame game.
Northeast
has been a safe haven for the terrorists as well as for the security agencies
to carry out atrocities without any accountability in different forms. In
larger parts of the northeast the draconian Armed Forces Special Powers Act is
in operation. Security of life and property, ‘….civil liberties, due
process, justice, and fairness….’ is a distant cry for the people of Northeast
in general and Assam in particular (Baruah 1999).
Way
forward
Though
no immediate solution is in sight, the state governments of Assam and Nagaland
are should initiate chief minister level dialogues on the border dispute
between the two states. These talks must be backed by utmost sincerity and
dedication in order to bring a sustainable solution to the protracted conflict.
It has been found that timely and prompt action by the neutral forces could
have stopped the ongoing violence. Time has come on the part of state
governments to accept responsibilities in a positive manner and to cooperate
with the Supreme Court mandated team to bring peace in the region.
Cleaning the
Ganga River
What Needs To Be Done Differently
The
central government has made cleaning of River Ganga one of its foremost
priorities. A former administrator involved with the Ganga Action Plan suggests
that a bottoms-up approach of involving local communities and stakeholders in
the regeneration of the river would be the only possible way in which the new
initiative will avoid the failures of the past.
Vijay
Jagannathan (Vjagannathan@wri.org)
is a senior fellow at the World Resources Institute, Washington DC.
Past
efforts at cleaning the Ganga River had invariably received political support
at the highest level in the central government, but the results were meagre
compared to the funds and administrative time invested. The author was
responsible for managing the West Bengal part of the Ganga Action Plan (GAP) in
the late 1980s, and so these observations reflect the benefit of 20/20
hindsight, as well as having been engaged in different aspects of water
management in several parts of the world.
The
key lesson learned from the past and ongoing World Bank financed effort is
quite stark: systemic factors, perpetuated by two centuries of state public
works departments’ (PWD) practices of “projectising” civil engineering
solutions cannot be reconciled with the desired outcome of a clean and well
maintained, mixed land use riverfront development which turbocharges local
urban economies by galvanising civic action to clean the river.
Mind
the GAP
The
GAP was conceived during Prime Minister Rajiv Gandhi’s term in office with
three components of central government funds to Uttar Pradesh, Bihar and West
Bengal. The largest and most capital-intensive allocation ended up supporting
investments in sewer lines, drains and in rehabilitating sewage treatment
plants (STPs) along the river. The second component was to build crematoria in
the large urban centres, so that the ancient practices of cremating bodies
using firewood (but often in practice dumped half burned into the river) could
be replaced with more sanitary and respectful disposal of the dead. The third
component was to beautify riverfronts or “ghats”, many of which had great
historic and cultural significance, but had over the centuries been reduced to
unsanitary bathing and washing spots for pilgrims and the urban poor alike.
Although
the second and third components of the GAP were of more direct local community
interest, the anxiety to disburse central funds quickly in the three states
(none of which were known for administrative efficiency) led the central
government to focus on the “hardware” part. This included how to monitor
investments in civil works schemes (for example, laying of sewer lines,
interceptor drains and refitting derelict STPs with new electrical and
mechanical equipment).
These
civil engineer driven efforts ignored the communities that potentially stood to
benefit, and there was even less interest in engaging urban planners,
architects and social activists who could have contributed their knowledge of
the existing urban form, explained the heritage potentials and helped us
understand the multiple layers of rights and interests of the various
stakeholders. The latter ranged from temple mahants, owners of local industries
and shopkeepers to the Doms, rickshaw pullers and tourist guides
who earned a livelihood by the river.
Furthermore,
while an expert committee was set up to evaluate the performance of STPs
throughout India, the lessons learned (notably that the STPs invariably failed
to perform after a couple of years of operation in all parts of India) were not
considered during the rush to disburse funds and report back to the Prime
Minister’s Office.
The
second component – the electric crematoriums – were designed and constructed
for operation by the municipalities, although the business model in other parts
of the world, where cremation is a common form of disposal, has invol-ved
public-private partnerships (PPPs). Bereaved families in India will vouch that cremations
are a harrowing experience, although experience from Japan and Korea suggest
that well-designed PPP contracts not only enable cities to get access to the
latest energy efficient technologies, but a more professional approach of
consoling the bereaved family members rather than be subject to extortion at
the time of their grief.
The
third component of beautifying the ghats was at odds with the global
experiences in successful waterfront development (in cities as diverse as
Singapore, Foshan, Baltimore and Bangkok). The common link in these successful
efforts was the generation of economic value from the redeveloped shore areas,
which was shared transparently with city residents who had housing, customary
and informal rights in those areas. All these efforts were preceded by careful
and systematic planning aimed at generating land value increases through mixed
use development while intensively engaging the communities that stood to
benefit.
The
failures of GAP have been widely accepted, and since 2011, the World Bank has
been supporting the Ministry of Environment and Forests in a second effort for
cleaning the Ganga through the $1.5 billion National Ganga River Basin project.
While the project document asserts that the design has learnt its lessons from
the failures of the GAP, its twin foci are on building capacity in the entire
river basin, while allocating core investments for civil engineering solutions
implemented through the very same state civil engineering agencies that failed
to deliver on the GAP promise. It is, therefore, not surprising in the least
that the latest project supervision (February 2014) report has concluded that
implementation performance has been unsatisfactory at a time when this flagship
programme is well into the third year of its implementation!
Successful
cleaning of the Ganga requires a different vision and leadership than what can
be expected from the “silo-ed” sectoral agencies in these relatively poor
performing state administrations.
I
would argue that actions are required on three fronts. These are:
·
To ensure that the incentives among
project implementation agencies are consistent with the prime minister’s vision
of a “Swachcha Bharat”.
·
To start with institutional
innovations that first secure community acceptance of a mixed use urban plan
that generates economic value along important cities on the Ganga’s riverbanks.
·
The leverage of technology and
financing opportunities linked to demand-driven urban development that helps
create incomes and employment, along with a better physical quality of life.
To
achieve this, I would suggest a four-step process in which the appropriate
sequencing of actions is critically important.
The
first step would be to have community engagement in assessing the situation,
and utilising the expertise of urban planners and architects to develop a
vision on protecting the river, as well as the cultural heritage along its
banks. The most important asset in a city is the waterfront land that residents
and the municipality own or have rights to. Any programme to clean the river
has to begin by exploring how best this asset can be leveraged to not only
reduce the outflow of liquid and solid wastes to the river, but also generate
economic value to local stakeholders.
An
illustration will be in order here. In ancient cities like Varanasi, there are
multiple layers of rights to land, which often lead to resistance when the
government seeks to acquire land. However, the same communities respond well
when future plans incorporate their economic interests. For example, riverfront
development has the potential of generating significant increases in land
values, and community support is robust when these increases are captured
and/or shared with them in a transparent manner.
Similarly,
areas of historic and cultural heritage have significantly higher long-term
economic benefits when they are protected from redevelopment, provided
innovative solutions such as selling of air rights to other parts of the city
safeguard these property owner interests. In this context, the Gujarat and
Maharashtra land pooling and readjustment mechanism (as opposed to the land
acquisition model followed in Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, Jharkhand and West Bengal)
provides a more practical institutional mechanism to secure community engagement.
Importance
of the Locality
The
next step is to reach agreements with communities, city and state
administrations and national governments on who will bear what costs in this
process of urban regeneration that accompanies cleaning the river. This
step will involve finding common ground and agreement (often as a consequence
of “tough” negotiations) on how responsibilities and economic benefits will be
shared between them and other stakeholders.
In
cities across the world that have successfully implemented such programmes, the
primary beneficiaries have been households, businesses and industries in
neighbourhoods that benefit from the urban renaissance. For example, Varanasi,
Allahabad, Patna and Kolkata are already major destinations for tourists, and
an improvement in the physical environment of the waterfront will greatly
enhance their attractiveness to tourists and investors alike. The key is for
residents of the city wards being able to share the economic benefits of land
value increases in an equitable and transparent manner.
There
are several planning tools available to ensure that this happens. These include
innovations in planning regulations, investigating options to preserve cultural
and built heritage while enhancing land value capture, utilising information
and communications technologies to plan, execute and sustain the development of
the waterfronts, along with tax (or betterment levy) implications, to name a
few. The widespread familiarity with social media makes deep community
engagement much more cost effective compared to what was possible even five
years ago.
The
third step is to delegate implementation responsibilities to organisations best
suited to deliver the desired outcomes. In other words, one should
apply the “subsidiarity principle” of managing change at the lowest appropriate
level. It is necessary to start with the mohallas and wards, and assign
implementa-tion responsibilities to neighbourhood institutions. The works
should begin with separation of solid wastes, move on to explore options for
improving sanitation and hygiene, and finally work out neighbourhood plans that
communities endorse fully.
For
example, in low-income communities of Brazil, the idea that these residents
need to manage their respective “horizontal condominiums” (just as rich people
maintain common areas in high rise or vertical condominiums viewed in TV soap
operas) has been a useful way of securing community engagement in improving
their neighbourhood physical environment.
Beyond
neighbourhoods, planners and policymakers need to assess which type of
institution is best suited to manage urban services. For example, funeral
infrastructure in countries where cremation is prevalent is best managed
through professional private sector entities, regulated by municipalities.
Other increasingly attractive technologies, such as conversion of waste to
energy or rooftop solar distributed generation need to leverage financing and
technology through PPPs. Mixed land use that safeguards the housing rights of
the urban poor has led to significant increases in land values in Bangkok city
without social conflicts.
Finally,
the Funds
The
fourth step is to release Government of India funds for engineering design only
as a last step, after the responsibilities, rights and contracting arrangements
have been worked out. The success of the programme will depend on
the extent to which the institutional and incentive structures are aligned to
the desired goal of cleaning the Ganga.
The
sequencing of the policy formulation and planning process will be the key
factor in achieving good results. Today, with the benefit of social media and
the availability of a lot of expertise both within India and in other Asian
countries that have undertaken similar programmes, the visioning and institutional
restructuring could be undertaken fairly quickly. The good news is that the
initial phases of agreeing on the urban plans, securing a common vision,
negotiating and finalising the work programme are time intensive, but not
resource intensive. However, once there is an agreement to move forward, funds
can be allocated and disbursed much faster, but linked to achieving the
outcomes specified in the work programme. These may involve leveraging smart
subsidies and viability gap funding for PPPs rather than channelling central
government resources to these relatively inefficient state agencies
Taking
on ISIS
There is
just no easy and clear way to defeat the Islamic State of Iraq and Syria.
Actions by the
Islamic State of Iraq and Syria (ISIS) have contributed to a deterioration of
the already catastrophic Syrian civil war and the possible disintegration of
Iraq. There is no question that this radical Islamist group, which thrives on
medieval methods, primeval ideologies and brutality, has to be militarily
defeated. How it is to be done is a difficult issue. The outcome of any event,
even if it leads to the defeat of the ISIS, seems to be one that is going to be
bloody, chaotic and one of further despair for the long-suffering people of
Iraq and Syria.
The rise of the
ISIS has been facilitated by a number of forces and circumstances, each having
its own set of consequences. The US invasion of Iraq and the post-occupation
policy of dismantling the secular state apparatus in the country in the hope
that a dependent nation could be created allowed the seeds of Al Qaida to be
sowed on the back of Sunni anger against the new establishment. The sectarian
attitude of the Shia-dominated governments led by Nouri al-Maliki as prime
minister fanned the rising waves of Sunni resistance so much so that former
Ba’athist forces sought an alliance with the battle-hardened ISIS which had
made significant advances in the Syrian civil war.
The Syrian civil
war had provided ISIS the opportunity to utilise the “great game” played by
various proxy forces intending to destabilise the Ba’athist regime of Bashar
al-Assad. Suffused with finances and weaponry supplied to the Syrian opposition
by various groups – financiers from the Gulf Cooperation Council countries such
as Saudi Arabia and Qatar – and helped by Turkish indulgence in allowing
foreign recruits to the ISIS cause to get free passes through the
Turkish-Syrian border, the group over-ran resistance from the Syrian regime and
took control over a large area in northern Syria. The US also played its role
in funding the rebellion against the Syrian regime, only to see the ISIS and
other allied forces reap most of the largesse.
Presently, the
ISIS has control over one-third of Iraq and a significant number of towns,
cities, and oil refineries in Syria, and has established a “de facto” state.
The ISIS sought to expand its territory into the northern and oil-rich areas
controlled by the Kurdistan Regional Government (KRG) beginning with the
capture of Iraq’s second-largest city, Mosul. In doing so, it subjected Iraqi
minorities – for example, the Yazidis – to brutality. The Yazidis were driven
into refuge in the Sinjar Mountains, as the Kurdish peshmerga (armed militia of the KRG)
withdrew protection when it could not take on the better-armed ISIS. It was
left to the Kurdish militias from Syria and Turkey – the People’s Protection
Units (YPG) and the socialist Kurdistan Workers’ Party (PKK) – to rescue a
large number of Yazidis, even as the US finally swung into action to protect
its KRG allies and assets. The pluralist and feminist YPG, an offshoot of the
PKK’s Syrian affiliates, has remained the most effective force against the ISIS
advance in Syria.
Despite
ideological differences, the Kurdish peshmerga has now formed a tentative
alliance with the PKK and the YPG – even as the US has sought to help the
alliance to take on the ISIS in northern Iraq. It is an uncomfortable position
for the US; it has proscribed and categorised the PKK as a “terrorist”
organisation. The PKK, which seeks a loose transborder confederation of Kurdish
areas, persists with insurgency in Turkey, a North Atlantic Treaty Organisation
member, although the two are also engaged in a tortuous peace process.
The US seems to
have a Janus-faced policy towards the ISIS. In Syria, the US prefers the heat
to remain on the Assad government and is reluctant to recognise the threat the
ISIS (and other Islamist forces such as the Al Qaida-affiliated Jabhat
al-Nusra) poses to Syrian unity. This has meant that the ISIS has used its
territorial acquisitions as buffers. With its financial resources and
US-sourced weaponry captured from the Iraqi army, it is a formidable opponent
to the Syrian government.
Iraq and Syria
are in shambles. The inability of the Iraqi government to stem the advance of
the ISIS has emboldened the KRG to assert its autonomy even more and has
increased the prospects of Kurdish irredentism. The radical Sunni character of
the ISIS coupled with its attacks on the Shia community has worsened the
already poor relations between the two communities in Iraq. The Iraqi citizenry
has no desire for further US involvement, which should rule out US
unilateralism. Besides, it is the unstated policy of the US to eventually
balkanise Iraq and Syria (Iran’s ally) that has resulted in the rise of the
ISIS in the first place, even as this was not intended. The US antipathy
towards Syria and differences in the UN Security Council do not guarantee any
agreement resulting in a reasonable resolution on intervention. The Gulf
monarchies realise the threat that the ISIS poses to their own retrograde
monarchies but are unable to look beyond their antipathy towards their
geopolitical enemy, Iran. Yet it is clear that the only way ISIS can be
militarily defeated is if the Syrian regime, the Iraqi government, the Kurds
and Iran (which too sees the rise of ISIS as a threat) are empowered and
unitedly take on the new caliphate.
The
Scottish Path to Independence
The
outcome of the Scottish referendum vote on 18 September notwithstanding, the
major legacy of the vote would be the transparent and democratic nature of the
process leading to the vote.
Pritam Singh (psingh@brookes.ac.uk) teaches at the
Department of Accounting, Finance and Economics, Faculty of Business, Oxford
Brookes University, Oxford.
The outcome of the referendum on Scottish
independence from Britain is certainly of huge significance for Britain, Europe
and even beyond but what has been missed in the debate on Scottish independence
is the significance of the process leading to the outcome. The process of
arriving at the outcome determines the legitimacy and the quality of the
outcome. In the Scottish case, the process has been so democratic, open, and
transparent that it is close to being exemplary. The decision to have a
referendum has been arrived at after a long period of debate and negotiations.
That Scotland, which became a part of the United Kingdom in 1707, has a
distinctive identity is very well recognised by all sides on the debate. This
recognition of distinctive identity was given further boost during Tony Blair’s
prime ministership when the long standing demand of Scottish people to have
their own parliament was accepted and the Scottish Parliament with devolved
powers started functioning in 1999. This devolved power was partly aimed to
weaken the demand for full independence which was at that time a minority
political tendency. The decision to create the Scottish Parliament by the
Blair government was not seen as a party partisan initiative but was arrived at
in a consensual manner by all sides of the Westminster-based political
establishment. The three mainstream British political parties - the
Conservative, Labour and the Liberal Democrats - all agreed on the need for a
Scottish Parliament with devolved powers.
The role of the Scottish
National Party
The Scottish National Party (SNP), formed in 1934, has
been the main champion of complete independence although subsequently the
demand for independence has been supported by the Scottish Socialist Party and
the Scottish Green Party. SNP remained a minor political current in
Scottish politics which for a long time has been dominated by the Labour party.
Even the establishment of the Scottish Parliament in 1999 did not enable the
SNP to become the largest, ruling political party although it emerged as the second
largest party and the main opposition party.
However, in 2007 the party emerged as the single largest
party in the Scottish parliament and formed a minority government with support
from the Green Party. In 2011, it gained an absolute majority in the Scottish
Parliament but still did not claim that its electoral victory should be seen as
an evidence of Scottish people’s support for complete independence. It put
forward a case for Scottish independence with a demand for referendum on the
issue. On the opposite side, the UK government did not ignore the electoral
victory of the SNP and gradually came to accept the need for referendum to
determine Scottish people’s choice regarding independence. This eventually
resulted in the UK government and the Scottish government agreeing in 2013 on
the arrangements for the referendum. 18 September, 2014 date was agreed for the
referendum vote and the question on the vote agreed was: Should Scotland be an
independent country? It was also agreed that there would be only two choices
for the voters: Yes or No. Although the SNP wanted a third choice of greater
devolution of powers to Scotland short of complete independence, it eventually
agreed to the UK government’s insistence on making a clear choice between Yes
and No.
Secession – Military
suppression or political solution?
There are not many examples of such agreed way of
resolving the demands for secession. The closest one before this has been the Quebec referendum to secede from Canada in which the secessionists lost the
vote. Most demands for secession get resolved either by military suppression of
the secessionist movement or by the secessionists winning the military battle
and achieving independence. In both cases, the legitimacy of the outcome
remains a contested issue. The most well-known example of peaceful secession
(“the velvet divorce”) is the separation of Czech Republic and Slovakia but
here the elites of the two regions agreed to separate; the democratic choice of
the people of the seceding region Slovakia was not ascertained.
In the case of Baltic States of Estonia, Latvia and
Lithuania, these states got independence through peaceful means of massive mass
mobilisation but no vote was allowed. Russia, the dominant region of the
crumbling Soviet empire, that had economic and political interests in keeping
control over the Baltic states, was not in a fit state-militarily and
politically- to suppress the independence moves of these states but now it
constantly resents in different ways, as seen most starkly in the recent
Ukrainian case, that these former Soviet republics managed to become
independent. The disputed outcome is significantly due to the lack of perceived
legitimacy of the process of achieving independence in the case of some of the
former Soviet republics.
The most recent case of secession (South Sudan) is also interesting from the view
point of the process of achieving secession. Although there have been violent
conflicts due to personal political rivalries, the legitimacy of the secession
has not been doubted due to the referendum vote that had led to secession.
Conclusion
In the Scottish case, almost every aspect regarding the
case for and against independence has been debated and most significantly in
the form of nationally televised debates between Alex Salmod, the First
Minister of Scotland, arguing the case for independence and Alistair Darling, a
Labour leader, arguing the case against independence on behalf of all the three
mainstream British parties. Whatever the outcome of the referendum vote on 18 September might be, the major legacy of the
vote would be the transparent and democratic nature of the process leading to
the vote. It would not be an exaggeration to say that Scottish example might
become the template for resolving secessionist disputes in the process. The
very high intensity of interest shown by Catalonia, the region with a demand
for secession from Spain, in the Scottish referendum debate and vote is a
pointer in this direction.
No comments:
Post a Comment